Industrial
Policy: Who Needs It?
Dr Gavin Lewis
For anyone
interested in the future trajectory of the South African economy, and of the
prospects for growth and employment, and indeed on favoured sectors for
investment in the future, a knowledge of this country’s industrial policy is
essential. This policy can be found in the Industrial Action Plans (IPAP), of which there have been several
renditions, perhaps the best known being IPAP 2. The problem is that IPAP 2 is
a very long and very complicated document. Too long, and too complicated. But
understanding it is critical, because it affects both our current and future
economic policies in detail.
Some countries do not regard a specific industrial policy as
essential. The current UK government prides itself on not having a formal
industrial policy, preferring to let the private sector take the lead – to the
consternation of the Business Secretary, Vince Cable, who wants a ‘joined-up’
growth and development strategy. In the UK that means picking sector winners
and assisting them with tax breaks, framing procurement policies, ramping up
infrastructure investment and focusing on exports – a post-crisis industrial
plan, in short.
So what does our IPAP say? It concludes that central to the
poor performance of the SA economy is a fall in production, as opposed to
consumption, and that this translates into a poor manufacturing performance.
Since manufacturing contributes 54% to production, reviving manufacturing, and
with it “decent” jobs, is the key but not the only focus of our industrial policy.
This approach includes a new thrust into green industries, rural development,
the Expanded Public Works Programme (EPWP) and infrastructure investment.
A central element of IPAPs is access to discretionary
finance, to fund developmental projects (e.g. infrastructure) that are not
currently attractive enough for voluntary private sector investment by offering
such prospects loans at reduced interest rates, or backed by state guarantees.
Here they run headlong into the fiefdoms of the Department of Finance and
National Treasury. So IPAP 2 is not
explicit as to additional sources of long term concessionary finance for
disbursement by the Industrial Development Corporation (IDC) , other than to
hint that this could come from state assets such as workmen’s compensation funds
(or retirement funds?) or – as more recently mooted by minister of economic
development and currently interventionist-in-chief Ebrahim Patel – through
development bonds.
Central place in the
IPAP 2 goes to the IDC, the state-owned development finance institution which
received R102 billion for this purpose in 2011, with the Development Bank of
South Africa (DBSA) in a supportive capacity: “…the public role of industrial
financing is to channel capital into productive [as opposed to consumption]
investments which directly and indirectly generate decent jobs and value
addition,” says IPAP 2. Raising funding through the full or partial privatisation
of State Owned Companies (SOCs) is however no longer considered an option,
reflecting the dominance of leftist influences in the current government. This
matters because it rules out raising finance for infrastructure from the
partial or full sale of SOCs, as Brazil is doing with considerable success
A further source of such assistance open to the state is
leveraging off public and, where possible, private purchases. The model here is
the National Industrial Participation Programme (NIPP) whereby in return for major state orders from
abroad for weapons such as civilian aircraft, ICT systems, nuclear power
plants, etc, above a certain minim incurs reinvestment obligations as part of
offset programmes by those from whom the purchases are made (the ‘obligors’).
The existing seven industrial sectors prioritised by IPAP 2
include automotive, plastics and pharmaceuticals, clothing, textiles and shoes,
bio fuels, forestry products, tourism/cultural industries, and business process
outsourcing (BPOs). More recently attention has been gained by the oils and gas
rig repair sectors and the boat building industry.
Conspicuous by its absence both historically and given
China’s insatiable demands for commodities, is one area which forms the
backbone of the SA economy, namely mining. Its absence speaks volumes about
picking winners and creating jobs. IPAP 2 added new sectors here – metals
fabrication, capital and transport equipment, green industries, in particular
solar panels, and agro-processing; but not IT services, engineering, legal and
medical services. It retains three additional high potential sectors – nuclear,
advanced materials and aerospace.
In the end what this aggressive industrial policy – at least
in theory- portends is that bureaucrats, not the market, decide where and how resources
will be channelled. And unless your bureaucrats are world class in their
fields, you are in trouble. This is especially the case when, as in South
Africa, the industrial policy emphasis is on big industrial investments,
whereas the job creating benefits of small business, universally acknowledged,
get hardly a mention and the binding constraints of poor rail, port and energy
infrastructure still loom so large as reasons for our poor economic
performance.
There are no guarantees of success in devising industrial
policies. There are many examples of failures of industrial policy. One is the
failure to rescue Britain’s motor industry, which no longer exists. Who
remembers British Leyland now? All too often, government bureaucrats fund so
called ‘zombie industries’ long after they have ceased to become viable. Propping up failing businesses that can never
be sustainable is a waste of resources. But politics intervenes, and in the
case of the ANC industrial policy is distorted to meet essential political
imperatives rather than economic ones. BEE crony capitalism and the policy veto
exercised by organised labour are also formidable constraints. Instead, the
IPAPs exclude some options for ideological rather than for business reasons.
Similarly, political
imperatives often preclude long term planning and the patience needed for long
term investments to bear fruit. Election cycles are shorter than economic ones.
A case in point is the abandonment of the Pebble Bed Modular Reactors (and the
scarce skills it retained) despite the hundreds of millions invested in it on
the eve of IPAP 2 which posited the nuclear industry as a high potential future
sector for the SA economy.
An associated danger of sector specific and company specific
industrial policy worldwide is that of capture of the benefits by a small group
of political insiders – crony capitalists. This is an obvious threat in South
Africa.
On the other hand there is a growing consensus that the “essence
of economic development is structural transformation, the rise of new industries
to replace traditional ones,” (The Economist, 17/7/10 ) and that
the acceptable face of contemporary industrial policy is where it seeks to
temporarily support brand new or infant domestic industries.
Success or failure then depends on a tailored, rather than a
shotgun approach; sector specific strategies rather than one-size-fits-all;
successful implementation by a competent state; a strict focus on costs,
including opportunity costs; and performance measurement, usually by monitoring
export performance which is difficult to fake. It also means having an exit
strategy for state-owned enterprises such as SAA and Denel, instead of
maintaining them at a permanent cost to the taxpayer.
But all of this has to happen after certain pre-conditions are
met, prominent amongst them a prior emphasis on strengthening
entrepreneurialism instead of suffocating it. A first priority should be to
build and maintain public goods that underpin business – getting the basics
right, like efficiently run ports, transport infrastructure and communications
network. In addition, slashing unnecessary red tape for business pays proven
dividends. In none of these is the ANC government distinguishing itself.
It is worth remembering the words of David Lewis (formerly
of the Competition Tribunal) that when it comes to industrial policy you “have
to be very selective and very focused in your interventions, and you want to
leave as much as you can to competitive forces” (Business Times
17/06/12). He should know.
The key issue instead is to focus on those businesses that are
already emerging and growing, and to assist them to grow faster without
second-guessing by bureaucrats who have no personal practical knowledge of
business and the market. In sum, industrial policy must always be market driven
for success. In our case the jury is still out.
No comments:
Post a Comment